Название: El sistema financiero a finales de la Edad Media: instrumentos y métodos
Автор: AAVV
Издательство: Bookwire
Жанр: Документальная литература
isbn: 9788491333173
isbn:
9 Je reprends ici l’analyse proposée dans Mathieu Arnoux et Gilles Postel-Vinay: «Territoires et institutions de l’assistance (XIIe-XIXe siècles): mise en place, crises et reconstructions d’un système social», dans Francesco Ammanati (éd.): Assistenza e solidarietà in Europa, secc. XIII-XVIII / Social assistance and solidarity in Europe from the 13th to the 18th centuries. Atti della XLIV Settimana di Studi, 22-26 aprile 2012, Florence, Firenze Universty Press, 2013, pp. 249-275, à partir des données rassemblées par Solène Jaugeat dans son mémoire de seconde année de Master: Études sur les rentes dans les établissements hospitaliers (Normandie XIIe siècle), EHESS, 2011.
10 Paul Le Cacheux: Essai historique sur l’Hôtel-Dieu de Coutances, l’Hôpital général et les Augustines hospitalières, depuis l’origine jusqu’à la Révolution, avec cartulaire général, 1re partie: L’Hôtel-Dieu (1209-1789), Paris, Alphonse Picard, 1895, p. XX.
11 Paris, Archives nationales L 968, L 970 et L 976.
12 Mathieu Arnoux: «Vavasseurs, dîmes et hiérarchies sociales dans les campagnes normandes (XIe-XIIIe siècles)», dans Cédric Jeanneau et Philippe Jarnoux: Les communautés rurales dans l’Ouest de la France au Moyen Âge et à l’époque moderne, Brest, Centre de Recherche Bretonne et Celtique, 2016, pp. 183-198.
13 Il s’agit de Thomas et Nicolas Lelégart (1266 et 1273), Roger de Hamars (1273), Guillaume Noé (1274).
14 François Neveux: «Villages et villes de Normandie», p. 160.
15 En 1260, les moines acquièrent de Thomas Macé un champ d’une acre dans la couture du «Long Boel» pour 9 livres, c’est-à-dire le prix d’un sextier et demi de froment de rente: Paris, Arch. Nat. L 968 (873).
16 Jean Meuvret: Le problème des subsistances à l’époque Louis XIV. Tome III: Le commerce des grains et la conjoncture. Texte, Paris, EHESS, 1988, pp. 97-143.
FOREIGN INVESTMENT IN PUBLIC DEBT IN THE NORTHERN LOW COUNTRIES, FIFTEENTH TO SIXTEENTH CENTURIES
Jaco Zuijderduijn Lund University
I
For many historians, polities’ capacity to borrow was crucial for the development of financial markets. Polities were usually among the most important borrowers in financial markets, and it has also been suggested they provided the investing public with a relatively safe haven for their savings. However, few studies have been able to establish how big the attraction of public debt was, and what effect this had on the redistribution of savings in emerging financial markets. This article asks to what degree public debt created by late-medieval polities helped to move savings from one place to another, and thus helped to bring together the supply of savings, and the demand for loans. To this end we focus on the geographic spread of creditors of several towns, and demonstrate how these towns managed to borrow from both citizens and non-residents. Late-medieval towns were not only active in local markets, but also had access to financial markets in their surroundings, and even those abroad. In theory such access to various financial markets should have brought about price convergence. To study whether this was the case, we also look at the interest rates polities paid on their public debt. Interest rates were quite similar, both towns, and even between towns and villages, which suggests that most polities had reasonably good access to at least several financial markets.
Interest rates on public debt gradually converged from 1300-1800: S.R. Epstein demonstrated a decline in interest rates in several regions of Europe, and more importantly, a convergence between these regions.1 This would suggest the existence of structures that in the long run helped to smooth spatial differences in supply and demand of savings. To be sure: why interest rates declined is still debated. Some scholars have suggested that this was due to an increase in coins per capita, at first because of depopulation in the wake of the Black Death,2 later because of improvements in silver production and due to increased mining activity in Central Europe, and the America’s after 1492.3 Others, following the seminal article by Douglass North and Barry Weingast on the English financial revolution, have claimed that interest rates could drop because improvements to the institutional framework of financial markets caused a reduction of risks and/ or the gradual integration of markets. Later, North even claimed that the level of interest rates is altogether the best indicator for the development of market structures.4 In this respect, some have also pointed at the gradual integration of financial markets, for instance due to the emergence of monetary unions.5 The latter views all assume savings were moved around more efficiently due to improved market structures.
A recent contribution to the latter strand of literature is David Stasavage’s study States of credit. Size, power and the development of European polities. Stasavage discusses one of the major puzzles of financial history: why did medieval city states and towns manage to borrow at lower cost than territorial states? He argues that the latter suffered from what we might call «diseconomies of scale»: due to large distances, it took relatively long to organize a meeting of the representative bodies responsible for debt management. In city states and towns, this could be done much faster, causing representatives to meet much more frequently. This allowed them to keep a close eye on public finance, which according to Stasavage made lending to city states and towns less risky. As a result these could borrow more and at better conditions than territorial states. Representatives of city states and towns also had a good reason to monitor public finance because they themselves were often major investors in public debt. These stakeholders thus had incentives to attend council meetings, and due to the low distances they had to cover, they could do this without much trouble. Stasavage’s main example is the General Council of Siena, which in the thirteenth century was also known as «Council of the Bell» because its members could simply be assembled by chiming a bell.6 Public finance, in Stasavage’s study, was a strictly local affair: polities borrowed from their citizens, investors lent to their city state or town. This may have been usual in polities such as Italian city states, where investing in public debt (via the so-called Monte loans) either was a privilege of citizens, or a duty weighing upon the wealthiest inhabitants, who were forced to lend.7 Under such circumstances the group of creditors indeed coincided with citizens. However, this was not at all the case in the late-medieval Northern Low Countries, where towns also borrowed from foreigners living out of town, and often even outside the province. Here, financial markets allowed СКАЧАТЬ