A Companion to Global Gender History. Группа авторов
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу A Companion to Global Gender History - Группа авторов страница 25

СКАЧАТЬ division of labor. Scholars studying evidence from physical and social anthropology and archaeology have argued that early humans subsisted primarily on vegetation gathered by either men or women and that both men and women hunted large game as well as small animals (Leacock, 1987; Arden, 2008). Archaeological evidence from the North America Dakotas suggests that women engaged in tool‐making, long believed to be a male specialization. And evidence from the Middle East points to flexible, relatively egalitarian roles of Neolithic farming communities (Bolger, 2010). By the sixteenth century in the Iroquois and Seneca communities of North America, women farmers provided the bulk of their communities’ food supply (Jensen, 1994; Brown, 1975) and in other Native North American groups, such as the Plains Indians, women’s participation in game drives and hunting was crucial to the survival of their communities (Klein, 1983). Early human societies also relied on cooperation between group members in food gathering, fishing, and distributing food, often lending women high status in their communities (Leacock, 1987; Goodale, 1971; Estioko‐Griffin and Griffin, 2000; Brettel and Sargent, 2000: 251). More clear‐cut gender divisions emerged over many thousands of years.

      Over time, the emergence of private property, complex societies and economies, and the conduct of wars and military campaigns in the ancient Middle East several thousand years before the Christian era gradually brought increased gender divisions and new forms of inequality. Of course, the growing complexity of societies did not by itself create gender divisions or inequalities, as the highly developed Egyptian Empire (3100 BCE–1000 BCE) illustrates. By the fourth century BCE in Egypt’s complex system of independent city‐states under the leadership of a pharaoh or king, linked by economic activity along with cultural and religious practices, literate men held both government positions and the dominant roles in the state bureaucracy. Elite women also served as queens, pharaohs, and priestesses. Non‐elite women worked as artisans and farmers, alongside men, and often in family agricultural labor in this society, where agriculture had developed as early as 8500 BCE. Women also engaged in the professions (Lesko, 1998). Women’s opportunities for holding public office diminished over time, but elites experienced the fewest gender divisions, and equality of men and women remained a formal characteristic of Egyptian legal, marriage, and inheritance systems. The relative gender equality of Egyptian society differed from other complex societies, such as Israel, Mesopotamia, and Asia where legal systems often established formal gender inequality.

      The same phenomenon occurred in Assyria (1900–1000 BCE) where dependence on trade and the growing importance of private property fueled Assyrians’ military aggressiveness, reinforcing male domination and the repression of women. Assyrian women could not own property, could not inherit, and generally assumed a “private,” rather than “public,” role in society. Although less severe in its regulation of women than Assyria, Hebrew society (1500–500 BCE) also illustrates how a high value placed on private property and the development of a strong military contributed to men’s dominant position in society. Although women farmed and contributed to the economic life of their families, they were excluded from the military and were legally and economically subordinate to their husbands. Overall, women experienced a relative decline in status as the societies of the ancient Middle East and Mediterranean became more highly militarized.

      Similar conditions prevailed in China where the simultaneous development of bronze tools – wheels and plows – improved the efficiency of agriculture, artisan production, and weaponry. As in Egypt and Hebrew society, men and women shared agricultural labor. But as in other increasingly complex economies and societies, women’s and men’s shared participation in the economy did not always translate into equality in other areas. Male warriors and government administrators in the Chinese kingdoms of the Shang (1500 BCE–1200 BCE) and Zhou (1200–700 BCE) enjoyed high status. Although women labored in agriculture and assumed domestic duties, in Han China (second century BCE) their economic contributions did not bring them high social status. Gradually, urbanization, social stratification, and the growth of more complex economies led to diminishing opportunities for women. The same was true in the highly stratified society of third‐century India, where the economic activities of virtually all women were circumscribed within the home.

      Historians speculate that with the expansion of the Roman Empire the authority and power of fathers diminished, allowing upper‐class women to exercise some political and legal control. In 212, the Emperor Caracalla gave all free men and women equal legal and economic rights. Some 300 years later the Emperor Justinian incorporated women’s rights – such as the right to own property – into his famous code of laws. But under the Christian Empire in the West, despite their recognition of the spiritual equality of men and women, and women’s ability to hold offices in early Christian groups, religious thinkers represented women as fundamentally inferior to men. Christianity’s ideas about gender later influenced women’s inferior position in society overall.

      The progressive militarization of societies accentuated the gender division of labor in which men’s skills as warriors became increasingly valuable for defending territorial integrity or for maintaining trade routes. Over several centuries, ideas about the desirability of a public role for men and a private role for women came to influence the discourses and cultural practices shaping gender and labor in everyday life. In Western Europe and Asia, the progressive devaluation of women’s work accompanied the gradual emergence of centralized, bureaucratic states.

      In the political decentralization that prevailed in Western Europe between the fall of the Roman Empire (about 476 CE) and the emergence of states in the thirteenth century, the political system known as feudalism revolved around ties of personal loyalty to leaders who sustained their leadership with private armies. Such a system had for a long time been the rule in China and Japan. Lower‐class men and women tilled the soil and plied СКАЧАТЬ