Crisis and Inequality. Mattias Vermeiren
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Crisis and Inequality - Mattias Vermeiren страница 18

Название: Crisis and Inequality

Автор: Mattias Vermeiren

Издательство: John Wiley & Sons Limited

Жанр: Экономика

Серия:

isbn: 9781509537709

isbn:

СКАЧАТЬ 1.9 offers an explanation of how SBTC raises income inequality through the operation of the price mechanism in labour markets for low-skilled and high-skilled workers. Due to the availability of new technologies and machineries that substitute for low-skilled workers, employers will demand fewer of these workers: graphically, the demand curve for low-skilled labour shifts to the left from D0 to D1 until a new equilibrium (E1) is reached, with lower wages and quantity (numbers) hired than in the original equilibrium (E0). Since the same new technologies and machineries are a complement to high-skill workers – such as engineers – there will be more demand for these types of workers: the demand curve for high-skilled labour shifts to the right from D0 to D1 until a new equilibrium (E1) is reached, with higher wages and quantity hired than in the original equilibrium (E0).

      From a neoclassical perspective, rising income inequality due to SBTC and economic globalization is both unavoidable and desirable. It is unavoidable because of structural shifts in demand for low-skilled and high-skilled workers in competitive labour markets, where wages correspond to workers’ marginal product of labour. But it is also to a significant degree desirable because people respond to incentives triggered by the market price mechanism: if people know that they will be rewarded with higher income, they will be more eager to develop skills (via education) for which there is high demand in the labour market. In the long term the greater supply of scarce skills will boost the growth potential of the economy by providing the human capital that is needed for technological innovation. There is a broad consensus among neoclassical economists that the long-term growth of GDP is dependent on labour productivity growth, which refers to the quantity of goods and services that a worker can produce per hour: ‘it reflects our ability to produce more output by better combining inputs, owing to new ideas, technological innovations and business models’.12 The availability of new machines and technologies has radically improved the efficiency of the production process over the past two centuries, raising the labour productivity of the average worker as well as the average standards of living (measured by GDP per capita) in advanced capitalist countries. Economic globalization is also believed to have boosted productivity by facilitating technology transfers and competition.

      The relationship between labour productivity and living standards has profound implications for public policy. According to most neoclassical economists, governments face a trade-off between equality and efficiency. First famously elaborated by US economist Arthur Okun in his 1975 book Equality and Efficiency, the existence of this trade-off has become so commonly accepted that it was labelled by Greg Mankiw as one of the ten Principles of Economics in his widely used introductory textbook:

      When the government redistributes income from the rich to the poor, it reduces the reward for working hard; as a result, people work less and produce fewer goods and services. In other words, when the government tries to cut the economic pie into more equal slices, the pie gets smaller. This is the one lesson concerning the distribution of income about which almost everyone agrees.13

      Power and institutions as determinants of inequality

      It would be wrong to believe that technological innovation and globalization are unrelated to inequality. Yet, from a political economy perspective, the neoclassical interpretation remains deficient for various reasons. As discussed above, income inequality has also increased within the top 10 per cent, between the 9 per cent and the top 1 per cent, which is difficult to explain on the basis of the theory of marginal productivity. Indeed, as Piketty notes in his book, ‘when we look at the changes in the skill levels of different groups in the income distribution, it is hard to see any discontinuity between the 9 percent and the 1 percent, regardless of what criteria we use: years of education, selectivity of educational institution, or professional experience’.15 The SBTC is even less well-equipped to explain differences in income gains within the top percentile (see table 1.1 above), whose members display even greater uniformity in skills than the top 10 per cent.16

      Moreover, the neoclassical interpretation fails to explain why the trajectory of inequality has been so markedly different in the Anglo-Saxon countries and the continental European countries. After all, these advanced capitalist economies have been more or less equally exposed to exogenous market forces like technological innovation and globalization, making it difficult to understand why wage differentials between high-skilled and low-skilled workers rose faster in the former group of countries than in the latter. In fact, the more egalitarian countries of Northern Europe have been more open to international trade and more export-oriented than the less equal Anglo-Saxon economies. So although technological change and globalization may act as powerful forces for income inequality, continued cross-national diversity suggests that other factors influence both the magnitude and the rate of change in inequality and top income shares: from a political economy perspective, the effects of technological change and globalization on the distribution of income and wealth in the advanced economies have been shaped and mediated by a variety of public policies and economic institutions that should be central to debates on inequality.

      The typical starting point in the political economy literature is therefore that the distribution of income and wealth in an economy is intrinsically political, in the sense that it is always determined by the distribution of political and economic power between different groups and classes in that economy. All capitalist economies have an intrinsic propensity to fuel economic inequality due to the asymmetric СКАЧАТЬ