Consumption. Mark Hudson
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Consumption - Mark Hudson страница 12

Название: Consumption

Автор: Mark Hudson

Издательство: John Wiley & Sons Limited

Жанр: Экономика

Серия:

isbn: 9781509535392

isbn:

СКАЧАТЬ humans actually behave. An early pioneer in this area was George Katona. He was particularly concerned that consumers’ desires and motivations were being overly simplified by the neoclassical economic assumptions and sought to discover what people were actually up to in their purchasing behaviour (Caplovitz, 1966). Based on his analysis of extensive consumer surveys, Katona deduced that, although consumers did attempt to inform themselves on economic matters, they were often slow to learn, which did not square well with the assumption of rational maximization (Hosseini, 2017: 132). Habitual behaviour and genuine decision-making were, according to Katona, the two most common determinants of purchasing behaviour. “The American consumer is a sensible person and is a discriminating buyer who seeks information and tries to understand what is going on. … This does not mean that he is an ideal rational man. Old stereotypes and attitudes persist even when no longer applicable and habitual behavior is very common” (Katona, 1964: 333). While individuals may not be rationally maximizing in the genuine neoclassical sense, they are sufficiently well informed to understand their desires and are able to realize them through their purchasing behaviour.

      Katona’s normative conclusions about the role of consumption in society portrayed the growing mass consumption of the early 1960s in an overwhelmingly positive light. According to Katona, the neoclassical assumption of non-satiation was backed up by his survey data. The more people have, the more they want. As we shall see in later chapters, some critics of consumerism place a negative spin on this for a variety of reasons, but Katona argued that these growing aspirations are beneficial for the individual and the economy.

      Another slight modification of neoclassical theory stressed that consumers’ utility comes from the characteristics that goods offer rather than the goods themselves (Ackerman, 1997: 659). To use an example from K. J. Lancaster (1966), all dish detergents are not equal. They contain a bundle of different characteristics that consumers may find more or less appealing, from their cleaning ability to their scent. If the characteristics of the dish soap are altered, for example, by adding a skin softener, then it should not be considered to be the same good, providing the same utility to consumers as a detergent that leaves your hands dry and chapped. Here, again, advertising plays an important and positive role for consumers. Given the complex collection of characteristics embodied in any good, providing consumers with information on the diverse and beneficial “consumption technology” available to them fulfills an important social function. As with Katona, the role of advertising illustrates Lancaster’s general interpretation of consumption, which is that people’s choice between characteristics leads to maximizing their utility.

      So, for Katona, Lancaster and Schumpeter, people are well served by an economy geared toward innovating new consumer products. For Lancaster, the inclusion of new features in a product actually changed the product, and if consumers approved of the new characteristic it would represent an increase in satisfaction from the same good or service. For Katona, the desire for more and more up-to-date consumer goods was not only good for those who had the wherewithal to purchase them, but it also provided a beacon of possibility and motivation for those who could not. Consumption beyond need, once associated with pride, vanity and wastefulness, became a virtue.

      This chapter examined the theories that put the best possible spin on shirt purchasing and the rest of our consumption activities. When we buy a shirt, it is because we want it more than other things that we could spend our money on. As put forward so long ago by Adam Smith, when we buy a shirt we enter into a voluntary trade with the seller that appeals to both parties’ self-interest. Consumers would only accept the trade if it improved their well-being. In making the exchange, the buyer is implicitly acknowledging that the shirt is worth more than the money for which it was exchanged. In this sense, no market-based consumption can be done without the consumer’s consent. The neoclassical introduction of rational, individual maximization implies that, in choosing the shirt, we are able rationally to weigh our options about what else we could have done with the money, from buying something completely different, such as a dinner out, to purchasing a shirt of a slightly different style and colour. This idea is as true for something as important as health care as it is for something arguably less life changing, such as a shirt.