Consumption. Mark Hudson
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Consumption - Mark Hudson страница 10

Название: Consumption

Автор: Mark Hudson

Издательство: John Wiley & Sons Limited

Жанр: Экономика

Серия:

isbn: 9781509535392

isbn:

СКАЧАТЬ This is expressed in the diamond–water paradox, in which Smith pointed out that people need water to live, resulting in a high use value. Yet the rate at which water can be traded for other goods – its exchange value or its price – was very low. Diamonds, on the other hand, had a very low use value compared to water, but a much higher exchange value (Smith [1776] 1976: 34). This paradox created a bit of a sticky contradiction because a good that was essential for life, and which people valued very highly in its use, had a much lower exchange value than a frivolous luxury. For the classical economists, exchange value was easy to measure by looking at the relative prices of two products, but it did not accurately represent the actual value to people. What did represent the actual value to people was particularly individual and, in the words of David Ricardo, “cannot be measured by any known standard” (cited in Stigler, 1950: 311).

      How those preferences are formed to create choices of one product over another, or between leisure and consumption, is not really the subject of inquiry. The social, cultural and economic institutions that might affect consumption are not examined by economics, although they might, perhaps, be the legitimate subject of another discipline (Ackerman, 1997: 651). For neoclassical economists such as Gary Becker, these non-economic disciplines can contribute best to social science by figuring out how preferences form, in order that they might be plugged into what he called the “economic approach” in which “all human behavior can be viewed as involving participants who maximize their utility from a stable set of preferences and accumulate an optimal amount of information and other inputs in a variety of markets” (Becker, 1976: 14).

      Alternative goals which explicitly acknowledge the importance of how income is distributed have been put forward, from egalitarianism to Rawlsian justice (which seeks to ensure a respectable income for the poorest members of society). Notwithstanding these pesky inconveniences to what the neoclassicals viewed as their purely scientific theory of the economy, it was nonetheless true that, as one economic historian put it, Jevons, Menger and Walras opened up a theory of consumption in which individual behaviour should be modelled as “rational, calculating maximization of utility” (Hunt, 1979: 237). These foundations have been further formalized and refined by subsequent authors, particularly Alfred Marshall, who measured the utility of commodities in terms of the price at which they exchanged and argued that the utility of individuals could be added together to measure the utility of all products (Stigler, 1950: 326). “We may regard the aggregate of the money measures of the total utility of wealth as a fair measure of that part of happiness which is dependent on wealth” (Marshall, 1890: 179–80). In other words, the amount of money you spend on a shirt is a direct measure of how much happiness you get out of it. Add up all the spending on shirts, pants, socks, Xboxes, Teslas and the rest, and you get a pretty solid assessment of happiness from all purchased consumption in society. You might also get some joy from picking daisies in a field, but economics hasn’t paid much attention to daisy-picking (at least it didn’t until the economics of happiness emerged and discovered that much of what makes us happy cannot be purchased).

      This particular species of consumer, based as it is on some fairly strong assumptions about human nature, was deemed a sufficiently unique animal that it merited its own scientific name – Homo oeconomicus. Consumers were modelled as (if not actually thought to be) actors capable of making rational choices in order to gain СКАЧАТЬ