Lazarus Rising. John Howard
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Lazarus Rising - John Howard страница 26

Название: Lazarus Rising

Автор: John Howard

Издательство: HarperCollins

Жанр: Биографии и Мемуары

Серия:

isbn: 9780007425549

isbn:

СКАЧАТЬ

      As a shadow minister, I had some hope of becoming a very junior minister in the new government. I guess, like all other shadow ministers, I had done all sorts of calculations in my head about my prospects, and I knew that Fraser wanted a smaller cabinet than the 32 or 33 which made up the shadow ministry. So I was not overly optimistic.

      Just after the meeting ended, John Bourchier, the chief whip, said that the Prime Minister wanted to see me in his office, and I got the clear impression that Bourchier knew I was to become a minister. I felt a keen sense of anticipation and my best hopes were realised when, a short while later, in the Prime Minister’s office, Malcolm Fraser told me that he wanted me to become Minister for Business and Consumer Affairs. I was tremendously excited and couldn’t wait to tell Janette.

      Whilst I thought that I had done a good job as a shadow minister, I knew that it was a fine judgement for a leader when choosing younger members in a new ministry. Malcolm Fraser and I have had our differences over the years and our relationship became very distant after I became Prime Minister, but I will always be grateful for the opportunity he gave me back in December 1975. It was a generous promotion at a critical time.

      Business and Consumer Affairs was a new portfolio arrangement which brought together many of the business regulatory functions of the federal government, including responsibility for the Trade Practices Act, the Prices Justification Act, and the Industries Assistance Commission and also, potentially, for the national regulation of companies and securities. Also included was the Customs Bureau, of which the Narcotics Bureau, carrying the federal fight against drugs, was part. The business community applauded this new grouping of responsibilities. The cluster of duties I had been given attracted intense scrutiny from the business media.

      The Fraser Government inherited a fragile economy. Inflation had soared to 14.4 per cent; unemployment stood at 5.4 per cent; the budget deficit had blown out to a projected 1.8 per cent of gross domestic product (GDP). Federal government spending had risen by a staggering 46 per cent over the two-year period of 1973–74. The Whitlam Government had been an incompetent economic manager; there was a near universal judgement that it would be a long time before Labor would again be trusted with the purse strings.

      Most of the senior members of the incoming Government — Fraser, Lynch, Anthony, Sinclair, Nixon, Bob Cotton, Peacock and Greenwood — had been prominent in earlier Coalition governments, and were heirs of the Menzies years, which had been ones of stability and prosperity. They had been, also, years of government regulation, an inward-looking Australian economy, high levels of tariff protection and a centralised wage-fixation system. This regulatory, activist role for government had seemed to work during that time. There had been much activity and full employment. Why then should that approach be changed?

      Maintenance of the status quo might have been justified if the world had not changed. The world, however, had changed quite dramatically in the early 1970s. The challenges for the Australian economy were quite different from what they had been previously; different responses were needed. The Whitlam Government had failed totally to realise this. The new Coalition Government would now have the opportunity of doing things differently, and better.

      From the perspective of my portfolio responsibilities, I felt that we needed to restore business confidence by cutting government spending, pruning business regulation, providing more incentives for investment, and tackling some of the excesses of union power.

      I appointed Paul McClintock, a Sydney lawyer and former president of the Liberal Club at the University of Sydney, as my principal private secretary. Paul had impressed me with his political courage in keeping the Liberal banner flying on a university campus during the early 1970s when, in the wake of debate over Vietnam and other issues, that was a particularly difficult task. Paul would later return when I was Prime Minister as head of the Cabinet Policy Unit.

      Quite early, I established the Swanson Committee of Review into the Trade Practices Act. I wanted the act loosened and made more business-friendly; one of the reasons the Australian economy was performing badly was that too much red tape and regulation had been imposed on the business community. Malcolm Fraser strongly supported the review.

      He did, however, backtrack on a promise to abolish the Prices Justification Tribunal. It was set up by Whitlam, and required large companies to obtain approval for price increases. It was impractical and a hindrance for business. Shortly after I became minister, Fraser rang and said it might be necessary to ‘give Hawke a win by going soft on our pre-election promise to get rid of the Prices Justification Tribunal'. Although it ran against our deregulatory thrust, I didn’t, at this early stage, question Fraser’s judgement, and we eased away from our commitment to abolish the tribunal. In those early months of government I believe that Malcolm Fraser thought that, with the odd gesture, he might win the grudging cooperation of the union movement.

      At that time the Trade Practices Act penalised secondary boycotts by companies, but not by unions. I thought that this was a double standard, and therefore wrong. Unions were, for example, placing boycotts on petrol deliveries by certain tanker drivers, which forced up the price of petrol for some motorists. If a company did something like that it would be penalised, yet the unions were not.

      I asked Thomas Swanson to look at this. Perhaps influenced by the conventional thinking, Swanson’s review did not recommend applying the secondary boycott law to unions. He did, however, suggest other changes which reduced the regulatory load on business, which we largely adopted. With Malcolm Fraser’s support I persuaded cabinet to bring unions within the secondary boycott reach of the Trade Practices Act, despite Swanson’s recommendation otherwise.

      Thus was born what became Sections 45(D) and (E) of the Trade Practices Act, which imposed substantial penalties on unions similar to those for companies that engaged in secondary boycott conduct. It was removed from the Trade Practices Act for a period of time under the Keating Government, only to be returned to the legislation when I became Prime Minister. It survives to this day.

      This was an historic change in the law affecting unions. It outraged the union leadership, particularly Bob Hawke. When the legislation was published I agreed to talk both to business groups and the unions regarding its provisions. At a meeting in Parliament House attended by Hawke as president of the Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU), as well as leaders of the public sector unions, Hawke glared at me across the committee room table and said, ‘If this goes through there will be blood in the streets.’ It was a nonsensical threat and one which was counterproductive. It confirmed my view that the proposal struck at the heart of the privileged position of the union movement, and I was more determined than ever that it should become law.

      As Minister for Business and Consumer Affairs I had administrative responsibility for the Industries Assistance Commission. Tariff policy was, therefore, another issue I confronted. Up until then I had supported the prevailing orthodoxy.

      This issue came to prominence after the Fraser Government, on 28 November 1976, devalued the Australian dollar by 17.5 per cent. Being a member of the economics committee of cabinet, I attended the cabinet discussion on devaluation. I strongly supported the decision, believing, as did Fraser, that Australian industry needed the competitive boost that the devaluation would confer on Australian exporters, because it would make their products cheaper on world markets. Likewise, it would help local manufacturers because the devaluation made imported products dearer and therefore less competitive.

      It was that last point which brought in tariffs. Existing tariffs on imported goods already made them dearer for Australian consumers, therefore it was argued that unless some of those tariffs were cut following the devaluation, an unfair additional burden would be placed on consumers and importers. The contrary argument, which I supported, was that it would be self-defeating to reduce tariffs significantly, as one of the reasons for the devaluation had been to help local manufacturers.

      Those СКАЧАТЬ