Crisis and Inequality. Mattias Vermeiren
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу Crisis and Inequality - Mattias Vermeiren страница 9

Название: Crisis and Inequality

Автор: Mattias Vermeiren

Издательство: John Wiley & Sons Limited

Жанр: Экономика

Серия:

isbn: 9781509537709

isbn:

СКАЧАТЬ ‘exogenous’ shock to the advanced capitalist system. The structural causes of the global financial crisis of 2008, by contrast, were ‘endogenous’ to this system: what happened in 2008 has to be understood as an outgrowth of the financialization of the economy and the outcome of growing levels of income and wealth inequality. In almost all rich countries, since the 1980s the gains of economic growth were distributed unequally. In 2016, the share of total national income accounted for by just the top 10 per cent of earners (that is, the top 10 per cent income share) was 37 per cent in Europe and 47 per cent in North America (even higher than in Russia and China, where the top 10 per cent income share was respectively 41 and 46 per cent of total national income).2 From 1980, income inequality increased rapidly in North America, while inequality grew more moderately in continental Europe. From a broad historical perspective, the rise in inequality marks the end of a post-war ‘Golden Age’ of egalitarian capitalism. Many lower- and middle-class consumers in the United States and other Anglo-Saxon countries like Ireland and the United Kingdom increasingly had to borrow to maintain and finance their consumption patterns in the face of stagnating incomes. In this way, the rise in inequality contributed to the global financial crisis of 2008 by leading to an unsustainable rise in household debt. Fiscal austerity reinforces these dynamics of inequality by cutting spending on social programmes that primarily benefit the bottom half of the income distribution. Finally, high levels of inequality can be a cause of low economic growth and ‘secular stagnation’, as even mainstream neoclassical economists at the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) have increasingly acknowledged.3

      There is a growing consensus that excessive levels of inequality could also endanger the endurance of liberal democracy. Based on their analysis of recent public opinion data, political scientists Roberto Stefan Foa and Yascha Mounk come to a sobering conclusion:

      Citizens in a number of supposedly consolidated democracies in North America and Western Europe have not only grown more critical of their political leaders. Rather, they have also become more cynical about the value of democracy as a political system, less hopeful that anything they do might influence public policy, and more willing to express support for authoritarian alternatives.4

      Since the 1980s, both voter turnout and trust in democratic institutions such as independent parliaments and judicial courts have sharply declined across the established democracies of North America and Western Europe: ‘As party identification has weakened and party membership has declined, citizens have become less willing to stick with establishment parties. Instead, voters increasingly endorse single-issue movements, vote for populist candidates, or support “anti-system” parties that define themselves in opposition to the status quo.’5 An increasing number of recent studies claim that the rise in ‘populism’ in most Western societies is closely connected to the rise in income inequality, the stagnation of middle-class wages and growing economic insecurity linked to financial and economic globalization.6

      Perhaps the best way to clarify the distinctive features of political economy as a field of study is by setting it against its main contender: neoclassical economics, which has become the dominant approach to study the economy in our contemporary society: it is the research tradition in which most economics students are nowadays educated. Neoclassical economics has become increasingly formalistic, developing mathematical models and quantitative methods that are completely detached from the social, political and historical context of economic dynamics in the real world. The global financial crisis exposed the failures of neoclassical economics.7 Understanding and deepening our knowledge of the global financial crisis and its longer-term causes and consequences should be central objectives in the social sciences, but neoclassical economics seems to have failed in reaching these objectives. In a famous event symbolizing this failure, Queen Elizabeth II of the United Kingdom asked, during a briefing by economists at the London School of Economics in 2008, why nobody had seen the crisis coming. Since then a growing group of students (and teachers) have started to complain that existing textbooks in economics had not done a sufficiently good job of explaining what exactly had happened and – even more importantly – why it had happened. In many countries, groups of students have demanded an overhaul in how economics is taught, with more pluralism and more emphasis on real-world problems like inequality and financial instability.

      In response to such criticisms, neoclassical economists usually reply that the main purpose of their mathematical models is to predict economic behaviour rather than formulate realistic assumptions about how the world really works. In his essay on the methodology of positive economics, US economist and Nobel laureate Milton Friedman argues that it does not really matter that the assumptions behind a theory are unrealistic as long as the theory’s predictions are correct:

      the relevant question to ask about the ‘assumptions’ of a theory is not whether they are descriptively ‘realistic’, for they never are, but whether they are sufficiently good approximations for the purpose in hand. And this question can be answered only by seeing whether the theory works, which means whether it yields sufficiently accurate predictions.8

      Friedman’s argument was reiterated by William Prescott – another Nobel laureate – in his 2016 paper RBC Methodology and the Development of Aggregate Economic Theory: ‘Reality is complex, and any model economy used is necessarily an abstraction and therefore СКАЧАТЬ