A Republic No More. Jay Cost
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу A Republic No More - Jay Cost страница 3

Название: A Republic No More

Автор: Jay Cost

Издательство: Ingram

Жанр: Историческая литература

Серия:

isbn: 9781594038686

isbn:

СКАЧАТЬ is a government that will produce public policy that favors well-positioned factions over society as a whole. This is a corruption of the republican form of government. To borrow that phrase from Madison and Hamilton, subsequent generations of Americans forgot about “the science of politics” as they eagerly expanded the scope of governing authority without considering whether a structural redesign would also be necessary.

      My research and thinking on the subject of political corruption did not end with the publication of this book. I’ve pondered the friendly criticisms it received as I have further researched American political corruption in the eighteenth century. On the basis of this reflection, I would add a refinement to my theory: certain kinds of governmental authority are more likely to generate corruption than others. The problem, then, is not so much the absolute level of power, but the kind of power that government wields.

      One of the main undercurrents of political debate during the first thirty years of the new government was whether it was appropriate for it to advance the general welfare through mediating factions. This concept is at the core of Hamilton’s economic agenda in the 1790s, which is discussed in Chapter One. Hamilton thought the moneyed class had a special role to play in the long-term prosperity of the nation, and he geared public policy specifically toward them. Madison and Thomas Jefferson deeply opposed this approach. While Madison had originally lobbied for a government of vast power, he was always skeptical of the idea that the government could advance the national interest in the long term by playing favorites in the short term.

      The Jeffersonian “Revolution of 1800” was, in many respects, a referendum on this very issue. But in an ironic twist, discussed in Chapter Two, the Jeffersonians eventually endorsed exactly this kind of power. The process happened slowly, over the course of a generation: Treasury secretary Albert Gallatin induced Jefferson to forbear against the Bank of the United States; Madison approved the charter for the Second Bank; and Henry Clay approved the idea of the federal government spending money directly on internal improvements. This was as much of a “revolution” as that which Jefferson wrought by defeating Adams in 1800, and it established the principle that it was legitimate for the government to pursue the general welfare by distributing benefits unequally throughout society—that government could help everybody tomorrow by playing favorites today.

      This is really one of the main ways the government now claims to promote the general welfare, by using social factions as mediators. They receive the direct benefits, and society at large benefits over the long haul—at least in theory.

      The problem with this policy is that the critique that Madison and Jefferson registered against it in the 1790s was entirely valid. Even if favoring particular social factions in the short term is indeed the only way to elevate what Monroe called “the spirit of the nation,” it still facilitates corruption. Those factions that receive special benefits are transformed into interest groups with a motive to lobby the government, and—thanks to their special benefits—the means to do so. Madison summarized the problem in a letter to Jefferson about the relationship between financial speculators and the government. They were no longer a faction in society, he said, but the “pretorian band of the Government, at once its tool & its tyrant; bribed by its largesses, & overawing it by clamours & combinations.”

      Insofar as big government is a direct contributor to political corruption, this is an important reason why. A government seeking to advance the general welfare through mediating factions is uniquely susceptible to political corruption. It transforms social factions into interest groups, which then cajole the government to continue distributing benefits to themselves, even if that is not good for the people as a whole.

       Preface

      TO BEGIN, a warning to the reader: this book is about political corruption, but it is not about Watergate. It is not about Abscam. It has little to say about Teapot Domes, and you will not find a word between these covers about Monica Lewinsky or Paula Jones. There are books out there that chronicle, in lurid detail, these events. This book is not one of them.

      All of those stories have a few items in common. Somebody breaks the law and (more or less) gets punished for it. There is a perp walk of some sort to reassure us that—in the end—good triumphed because indecency was exposed for what it was. Even if the bad guys go to the grave escaping the long arm of the law, the arm of the historian reaches farther still, and the audience can rejoice in the culprits’ reputations duly suffering for their civic transgressions.

      This book, rather, has much more to do with the guys who got away with it, in particular the guys who flaunted it while getting away with it. In the 1890s, as Congress was writing tariff laws governing sugar, Pennsylvania’s political boss, Senator Matthew Quay, admitted that, yes indeed, he was speculating in the sugar markets, that he would go right on doing so even as he voted on the sugar tariff, and there wasn’t a damned thing anybody could do about it, thank you very much. He was right. A decade later, William Randolph Hearst exposed his successor, Boies Penrose, as being on the take from Standard Oil. Nothing came of it, and Penrose was reelected several times thereafter. He died in office.

      Why did nothing happen to those men? Simple: they were not breaking the laws of their day. That is the fascinating feature about corruption—often, it has absolutely nothing to do with illegal activity. There are plenty of ways, as we shall see, to be corrupt without being criminal. More often than not, the criminals merely lack self-control or self-awareness. That makes them easy targets for rebuke, and thus reasons to feel good about ourselves and our government.

      But as Quay and Penrose prove, the law often has trouble keeping up with corruption, in no small part because the people who write the laws like it that way. Perhaps George Washington Plunkitt, a sachem (or boss) of New York City’s Tammany Hall about a century ago, puts it best:

      Everybody is talkin’ these days about Tammany men growin’ rich on graft, but nobody thinks of drawin’ the distinction between honest graft and dishonest graft. There’s all the difference in the world between the two. . . . I’ve not gone in for dishonest graft—blackmailin’ gamblers, saloonkeepers, disorderly people, etc.—and neither has any of the men who have made big fortunes in politics.

      There’s an honest graft, and I’m an example of how it works. I might sum up the whole thing by sayin’: “I seen my opportunities and I took ’em.”

      Just let me explain by examples. My party’s in power in the city, and it’s goin’ to undertake a lot of public improvements. Well, I’m tipped off, say, that they’re going to lay out a new park at a certain place.

      I see my opportunity and I take it. I go to that place and I buy up all the land I can in the neighborhood. Then the board of this or that makes its plan public, and there is a rush to get my land, which nobody cared particular for before.

      There was nothing honest about Plunkitt’s fraud, but he was onto something in drawing the distinction he did. “Dishonest” graft is criminal activity that harms people directly, whereas “honest” graft is technically legal, and the victim is the common good, not a particular individual. What Plunkitt was doing in his day would be outlawed today, but honest graft nevertheless survives, in different forms, always changing to stay one step ahead of the law.

      Why is this the case? The answer to that question is the subject of this book.

      So, what follows is not a tale of heroes and villains. Herein, you will not find clear-cut victories, glorious moments of truth being spoken to power, or exhilarating climaxes when the hard-charging civic hero triumphs and the citizen’s faith in government is restored. If you’re looking for that, go read All СКАЧАТЬ