Yet some element of generational distinction seems to be playing an undeniable role in the logic of the present. So, what do we make of this? A useful direction here was indicated in the Financial Times (2019), which is always more willing to put critical analysis to work for the preservation of capitalism. Featuring a picture of economist and former chair of the US Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke juxtaposed with one of millennial Democratic politician Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez, one of its opinion pieces stated that ‘Quantitative Easing was the Father of Millennial Socialism’. Quantitative easing is a policy that central banks in many countries have relied on over the past decade to rekindle economic growth and escape from the Great Recession that ensued in the wake of the financial crisis of 2007–8. It works on the idea that, if central banks push large amounts of liquidity into the financial system, banks and other financial institutions will lend more liberally and so spur investment, growth and employment. But one of the main points of critique of these policies has been that this transmission mechanism is not in fact working very well, and that in practice quantitative easing has propped up the values of financial assets without translating into higher rates of employment and growth (Blyth 2013; Gane 2015). That is to say, quantitative easing is often seen as working to enrich the owners of financial assets (often pejoratively referred to as ‘rentiers’) at the expense of those who have to work for a living.
The same Financial Times piece continued with an observation on the generational effects of property prices. Noting the dramatic divergence between wages and property prices in large cities over the past decade (not just in New York and San Francisco but also in many smaller urban centres), it concluded: ‘The young are locked out.’ In almost all large Western urban centres, property prices have reached levels that make renting very expensive and put home ownership effectively out of reach for many. Although housing is by no means the only asset that plays an important role in the contemporary political economy, it plays a central role in the story that we tell in the following pages. Property inflation in large urban centres is the linchpin of a new logic of inequality.
Property price inflation is not limited to the past decade. In major cities across the Western world property prices have been on the rise for several decades. If this problem had been limited to the past decade, we would just be looking at a particularly inappropriate set of policies conceived by incompetent or corrupt elites. That would be bad enough, but we might reasonably hope that greater awareness of the issue would lead to democratic pushback and a reversal of quantitative easing policies. But the problem is of longer standing and reaches deeper into the fabric of social life. As we will see in the following pages, quantitative easing is only a more explicit version of financial policies that have been pursued since the 1980s that aim to make asset ownership profitable. We should also not be too quick to cast this as a project that aimed to enrich a tiny elite at the expense of the rest of the population, as the current focus on the runaway wealth of the 1% would suggest. The phenomenon of the 1% pulling away from the rest of society is all too real, but it is so thorny and intractable precisely because it is anchored in a wider institutional and social configuration that has generated particular constituencies with a vested interest in these sorts of policies.
It is therefore important here not to reach too quickly for a critique of ‘rentierism’. It may be a useful means of expressing moral opprobrium and voicing concern about a world that allows some to receive income without having to work for it, but its analytical edge is blunt. The critique of rentierism is long-standing. It has for many years been a favourite tool of the left, whether of middle-of-the-road progressive reformists, labour politics, or more radical currents. Indeed, it had been one of John Maynard Keynes’ stated concerns to ensure the ‘euthanasia of the rentier’ (Keynes 1936: 376), and it seemed to many that mid-twentieth-century capitalism had delivered precisely this, bringing capitalism in line with the needs of working people. But the past decades have done much to erode this sense that capital can work to advance the interests of society as a whole. Left-wing critics have relied on the critique of unproductive rentierism to criticize neoliberalism since its inception (Duménil & Lévy 2005; Onaran et al. 2011; Standing 2016), but in recent years the critique of rentierism has returned to mainstream public debate with Thomas Piketty’s (2014) book Capital in the Twenty-First Century.
Piketty sees the growth of inequality primarily in terms of the rentier fortunes of those at the very top. In this book we argue that this is only part of a larger story that we need to understand. By framing present-day trends in terms of a return to the days before the Keynesian euthanasia of the rentier, we argue that Piketty ultimately understates the qualitatively different logic governing the mechanisms of inequality production in current times. It is certainly important to understand how the escalation of inequality at the very top has been able to continue for so long in a democratic society, but we need to recognize it as part of a wider, more structural reconfiguration of patterns of inequality. After all, the advent of mass democracy was one of the key pressures that led to the levelling policies of the New Deal and post-war state. To a significant extent, the ‘rentier function’ has become embedded across social life as a whole. But the growing awareness that owning assets often pays more than working for a living has not yet been translated into a new understanding of class and inequality. Although the phenomenon of property inflation has received plenty of commentary, when it comes to thinking about class, inequality and stratification in more systematic ways we often tend to revert to older models based on work and occupation.
The key element shaping inequality is no longer the employment relationship, but rather whether one is able to buy assets that appreciate at a faster rate than both inflation and wages. Employment remains an important factor as it shapes the ability to purchase assets (e.g. the ability to service a mortgage), but it is increasingly only one among other factors. Of course, income from work remains vitally important for many people as a way to access subsistence goods, but the important point is that by itself it is less and less able to serve as the basis of what most people would consider a middle-class lifestyle. Asset appreciation has been engendered by a specific institutional nexus that has fundamentally redrawn the social structure – such that asset ownership is now becoming more important than employment as a determinant of class position.
The millennial generation is the first to experience this reality in its full force. So, the generational aspect is important not because it produces a uniform experience of social life or a clean divide between different generations (as a naïve approach to generational analysis would imply), but precisely because it is where the economic fault-lines that four decades of neoliberal fiscal and financial policies have produced are becoming visible. After all, some millennials have access to parental wealth (often itself the result of property inflation) that allows them to buy into dynamics of asset inflation. What we are seeing in the present era is the growing importance of intergenerational transfer and inheritance for the determination of life chances.
Crucially, however, this is not best understood as a return to an earlier era, when property was passed on (generally among men) from one generation to another in a more or less stable and mostly uneventful way. Inheritance is no longer a simple transmission of property titles, but increasingly a strategically timed transfer of funds that need to be leveraged and put to work in the speculative logic of the asset economy. This new logic of inequality has mixed ‘hypercapitalist’ logics of financialization with ‘feudal’ logics of inheritance to reshape the social class structure as a whole. The generational dimension interacts with the speculative logic of the contemporary financial system to shape asset-based lifetimes.
Plan of the book
In the following chapters, we will show how the changing role of assets has been responsible for the creation of a new logic of inequality in Anglo-capitalist societies. In the next chapter, ‘Asset Logics’, we explain the importance of thinking of the contemporary economic system as dominated by the logic of assets. We differentiate our approach from competing perspectives that tend to overemphasize the orthodox image of the market and in particular the idea that liquidity is an inherent aspect of financialization. Such perspectives neglect the fact that participation in the financialized economy often СКАЧАТЬ