The New Environmental Economics. Eloi Laurent
Чтение книги онлайн.

Читать онлайн книгу The New Environmental Economics - Eloi Laurent страница 11

Название: The New Environmental Economics

Автор: Eloi Laurent

Издательство: John Wiley & Sons Limited

Жанр: Экономика

Серия:

isbn: 9781509533831

isbn:

СКАЧАТЬ experience greater well-being. CO2 emissions are growing a little faster than human development, but at a slow pace, extraction of natural resources grows at the pace of human development and Gross Domestic Product (GDP) reflects, exaggerating a little, a new prosperity of the human species, seemingly compatible with the preservation of its habitat, the biosphere.”

      During the second period, between 1950 and 1980, the great desynchronization begins: While the growth of human development slows down and is gradually caught up by that of the population, CO2 emissions and GDP are racing and natural resources extraction is multiplied by 2.5. At the end of the period, in 1980, CO2 emissions and GDP grew by a factor of ten compared with the beginning of the twentieth century, tripling the pace of population growth and human development.

      The third age of human development is the time of illusion: While population and human development are stabilizing at the same rate of growth, CO2 emissions continue to grow much faster than both, and natural resources extraction doubles again, while GDP, completely disconnected from human reality, masks the gravity of the ecological crisis (in that period, biodiversity declines substantially).

      The increase in human development in the second half of the twentieth century has been achieved at the cost of environmental degradation (in the form of CO2 emissions) four times higher than in the first half of the century, even though the population increased only slightly more than in the years between 1900 and 1950 (2.4 against 1.6). It is therefore mostly the qualitative means of human development that are in question – and not just the quantitative demographic pressure – in the explosion of post-Second World War environmental degradation. The beginning of the twenty-first century is even more “inefficient” when we relate human well-being to its ecological cost. Emissions growth increases at its highest rate ever (almost 75%), contrasting with the growth of human well-being and population (only 10%) and up to 1 million species are threatened with annihilation because of human activity.

      To sum up: Between 1900 and 1950, it was necessary to triple CO2 emissions to obtain a doubling of human development. Between 1950 and 2000, this same doubling required more than a quadrupling of CO2 emissions. At the beginning of the twenty-first century, a doubling of human well-being would be achieved at the cost of a multiplication by almost eight of the CO2 emissions responsible for climate change. In other words, Malthus has his accounting revenge and we are faced with a new crisis of paces: To the now synchronized arithmetic growth of the population and well-being responds the geometric progression of environmental degradation that will eventually overcome human recent and fragile prosperity.

      This Malthusian method is the implicit choice made by human societies at the beginning of the twenty-first century: About 90% of the so-called natural catastrophes of the last twenty years are linked to climatic phenomena, and they have affected the existence of 2.3 billion people, who live for the most part in the poorest countries on the planet. The current rate of degradation of the biosphere promises the world’s most vulnerable hell on Earth.

      Malthus leaves us with a haunting intuition of our sustainability crisis and a dismal response to it. David Ricardo, over whom Malthus exerted a strong intellectual influence, offered more humane responses in dealing with the inescapable limits of human development on a finite planet.

      “Planetary boundaries” are quantitative thresholds “within which humanity can continue to develop and thrive for generations to come.” Crossing these boundaries entails the risk of generating large-scale abrupt or irreversible environmental changes. Scientists warned us recently that “Four of nine planetary boundaries have now been crossed as a result of human activity: Climate change, loss of biosphere integrity, land-system change, altered biogeochemical cycles (phosphorus and nitrogen).” Two of these, climate change and biosphere integrity, are “core boundaries.” Significantly altering either of these would “drive the Earth System into a new state.”7 This is certainly breakthrough science, yet the classical economists from the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries had the intuition that human development was in fact constrained by the scarcity of Nature.

      What has been referred to as the “grandiose dynamic” of the English classical school (whose major triad includes Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill) is based on the assumption of the domination of Man by Nature. In the view of the authors, Man does not (cannot) destroy Nature: He takes advantage of his fertility but, in return, Nature imposes on him his rhythm of exploitation and his finitude, and promises him a stationary state as an horizon. According to the classics, economic growth is only possible as long as all available land is not exploited, agricultural productivity being a gift that cannot be manipulated by technological progress.

      The work of David Ricardo (1817) is indeed profoundly marked by Malthus’ (wrong and not so wrong) reasoning. But Ricardo refined it considerably by formulating his theory of agricultural rent. In his analysis, the scarce resource is, quite naturally, agricultural land whose limited availability in the United Kingdom was glaring, while the industry just began its take off. Ricardo framed his famous reasoning in terms of “differential rent”: The most fertile lands are the first to be cultivated, but, as the pressure of demand increases because of the increase of the population, less fertile land must be exploited. Because these new lands are less productive, their unit cost of production is higher, so the selling price required for production on these new lands is also higher. But the market price being unique, the owners of the most fertile land benefit from a “differential” rent. “Diminishing returns” occur because of the lower productivity of the lands gradually being cultivated under the pressure of the consumption of their yields by a growing population.

      Ricardo saw globalization and technological progress as solutions to the law of diminishing returns. But he had more confidence in trade than in technology. Considerably refining and extending the “absolute advantages” of Adam Smith,8 he greatly enlarged the circle of countries that could beneficially take part in globalization (potential partners of his home country). He also thought that if agricultural innovations would accelerate (as will be the case throughout the twentieth century), then diminishing returns could be overcome. But Ricardo envisioned a “steady state” of the economy, at the very end of Chapter V of the Principles of Political Economy, where neither globalization nor progress in techniques operate any longer. John Stuart Mill will push the idea much further in the middle of the nineteenth century, all the while the first industrial revolution was booming all around him.

      In СКАЧАТЬ